Brown moves the goalposts |
|
|||
Donald
Hirsch |
Monday 12th March 2001 |
||
|
Both main parties are now
promising extra cash for the disadvantaged. For British politics, that
represents an astounding change, writes Donald Hirsch
By delivering a
remarkably unremarkable pre-election Budget, Gordon Brown showed two things.
First, his confidence that his image as a steady hand at the economic tiller
would count for more than any short-term electoral bribery. Second, that his
brand of quiet redistribution has in four years so transformed the political
landscape that measures which would have astounded people yesterday are today
taken for granted.
After Brown's first big Budget in 1998, the New Statesman noted that
"for the first time that many of us can remember, the Chancellor made a
big, explicit give-away to poor families, and made it look respectable".
Each of the next three Budgets followed the same course of giving more to the
poor, and much less to the better-off. Treasury charts showing how Budget gains
have been concentrated on the poorest 20-30 per cent of the population have
become so familiar to the pundits that they have forgotten how novel they
seemed only three years ago.
The big change over this period has been the extension of such largesse to more
groups. The first beneficiaries, poor working families, continue to be the most
favoured, but Brown has also been exceptionally generous, by past standards, to
non-working families, and now to pensioners and all families with very young
children. Indeed, had it not been pre-announced, this Budget's deal for
pensioners would have made it considerably more exciting, representing the
biggest single income transfer to a large low-income group that seasoned
commentators can remember.
Gordon Brown's record needs to be considered in a long-term perspective. In the
1980s and early 1990s the poorest groups did not share in the fruits of
economic growth, in large part because chancellors raised benefits only in line
with rises in prices, not rises in earnings. The result was that while average
earnings rose 20 per cent in real terms, people who depended on benefits, in
particular large numbers of pensioners but also many families on the breadline,
had little or no real increase.
The more Brown is lobbied for a formal restoration of a link between rises in
the basic pension and the growth of earnings, the more he resists it. But look
at what has actually happened between 1997 and 2001.
Average earnings are 20 per cent higher in cash terms than when Labour came to
power; 10 per cent higher after adjusting for inflation. The poorest pensioners
in 1997 had their income topped up, if necessary to a minimum £68.80 a week; by
next month they will have reached £92.15. This is a 22 per cent real-terms
increase - so members of this group have not only kept up with earnings growth
under Labour, but made up about half the ground they lost under the
Conservatives. Their incomes had fallen by 20 per cent relative to average
earnings; they have regained 12 per cent. For some low-income working families
the rise has been even greater.
These kinds of transfer, Brown's largest, are all based on means tests, which
can bring serious problems in their wake. Give poor working families big income
top-ups and you make it more worthwhile to be in work, but potentially less
worthwhile to better yourself in work by lengthening your hours or training for
better-paid work. This is because for each extra pound you earn, you lose a
hefty chunk of the means-tested top-up. Similarly, too much reliance on means
testing for pensioners makes it hard for many of them to improve their net
income in retirement by contributing to pension schemes.
Brown is aware of this problem and is starting to take measures to counter it.
The pensioner credit allows people to keep 60p of each pound in their own
pensions rather than having it "clawed back" by losing part of their
means-tested entitlement. The basic state pension itself is being raised faster
than earnings, although these rises will not restore its relative value even to
1997 levels. For poorer working families, increasing the minimum wage should
help a bit, in terms of their ability to increase income earned in their own right
rather than relying on means-tested transfers that disappear as soon as they
get a bit better off.
How much has Brown's redistributive habit transformed political thinking more
widely? The Conservatives have been highly critical of the extension of means
testing, yet talk far more now about helping specific groups in the name of
social equity than they have for some decades past. Compare, for example,
Michael Portillo's remark before the last election that people had better start
making their own pension provision because the state pension's value would soon
be "nugatory", to the promise from the present social security
spokesman, David Willetts, that the Conservatives will outstrip Labour's
present increases.
Yet the benefit of some of the Tories' proposals for poorer groups could be
undermined by the Labour means testing that they criticise but would find hard
to remove.
Take, for example, their "transferable tax allowances" for married
couples with children where there is only one earner (the "traditional
family"). The difficulty with increasing that or any other tax allowance
is that Brown's means-tested credits for the working poor are assessed on net
(post-tax) income. So reducing other tax liabilities would make people look
better off and therefore reduce their tax credit entitlement (unless a specific
exception was made). In the case of the transferable allowance, this means that
to anyone receiving the working families tax credit it would be worth only
£450, rather than £1,000 for better-off families. In the case of the Tories'
proposed increases in the state pension, they have stated that such clawing
back would not take place - showing that they recognise the problem, but adding
to the complexity of the system.
Both parties now see political mileage in promising extra cash for
disadvantaged groups, a far cry from the Lawson years when the big prize was
cuts in the basic rate of income tax. But, as the table underlines, Labour's
emphasis is more squarely on people near the bottom, while the Conservatives
verge more towards the middle. Yesterday's received political wisdom would not
have seen this as a winning electoral formula for Labour.
After the Budget: red and blue water? |
|||
Group |
Labour emphasis |
Conservative emphasis |
Spot the difference |
Families |
Children in any working family with low income Integrated child credit will give the same per child for poor
families in and out of work |
Married non-working mothers Transferable tax allowance to make their husbands better off |
Tory allowance would be worth most for middle earners. Poor families on Labour tax credits (it's
those who earn up to about £17,000 a year with two children) could have over
half of allowance clawed back. |
Pensioners |
Guaranteeing minimum income; ad hoc rises in basic pension Means-tested level has risen 22 per cent in real terms since 1997 |
Taxing pensioners less; ad hoc rises in basic pension Raising pensioners’ tax allowances by £2,000 |
Both parties trying to ensure that better basic pensioners won't be
clawed back through means testing. But Conservative emphasis on reducing tax burden affects only the
rich 40 per cent who pay tax |
Savers |
Encourage people with lower incomes to save ISAs and stakeholder pensions, but possible measures to help poor
acquire assets (eg “baby bonds”) not
yet implemented |
Not taxing savings Nobody except higher rate tax payers would have to pay tax on savings |
Both parties have similar aims, but second -term Labour could
introduce important new encouragement for poor. Conservative scrapping of tax
may mean little for poorer groups, since ISAs already allow up to £7,000
tax-free |