The white paper's move
towards an admissions free-for-all is bad news for
underprivileged families, says Donald Hirsch.
If schools are to become "autonomous", what is to stop a
complete free-for-all in admissions?
The new schools white paper's tortured attempt to answer
this question tries to reconcile terms like "competition",
"fair admissions", "strategic leadership" and "choice". But it
does not adequately resolve the central problem, which is that
the more you give schools autonomy and urge them to compete,
the greater the pressure on them to define their own "markets"
by seeking to admit the easiest to educate.
Perhaps the starkest consequences of school autonomy in
admissions arose from New Zealand's market reforms of the
1990s. Every oversubscribed school was allowed to formulate
its own admission policy provided it did not contravene basic
human rights (for example by being overtly racist).
This meant, for example, that there was nothing to stop a
school from favouring children from an asymmetrical catchment
area drawn to include the most privileged neighbourhoods. It
also made it possible for schools to use criteria such as
interviews, and to give no priority to local children.
The result appears to have been a rise in the tendency for
well-off, white families to access the best schools and in
some cases for children to be denied entry to any local
school.
A reform of this system by a new government in 2000 obliged
schools to give priority to local children.
One thing that we should have learned from this story, and
our own messy experience of school choice in the past 15
years, is that publicly-funded schools cannot be left to
define their own markets.
However autonomous we wish to make them, it will not work
to allow schools to pick and choose whom they educate. If we
do this under a system of governance dominated by parents'
interests, the result will be exclusive school communities
using public money to support their own sectional interests.
Without a co-ordinated system ensuring that places are
allocated fairly, there are bound to be huge inequities in
access to good schools. Many children will also fall through
gaps in provision and be prevented from attending a school
near their home.
The Government recognises these considerations and
acknowledges the importance of "fair admissions". The role of
overseeing such fairness is to be transferred from the
independent school organisation committees to local
authorities, while individual schools can control their own
admissions. The idea is to put the local authority in some
form of strategic role, and to reduce its role as a provider.
This remains a messy arrangement as some places will
continue to be allocated by the local authority, and, when it
makes its own proposals for admissions, decisions will be
overseen by the independent schools adjudicator.
But can any regulating body adequately co-ordinate school
places offered by a bewildering array of competing
semi-autonomous institutions?
Each child is physically able to access only a limited
number of schools, which are now defining themselves by
various overlapping criteria: their faith, their specialism,
their geographic intake. In such circumstances, there seems to
be no systematic way of ensuring that every child ends up in a
suitable school.
Local authorities will have some power to ensure that
schools follow the admissions code of practice, introduced in
2003. This does constrain the extent to which schools can use
unfair criteria to allocate places, or even ignore completely
the advice of the local admissions forum.
Yet school places cannot be planned or co-ordinated through
negative measures. The partnerships among local schools needed
to produce decent opportunities for all a community's children
rely on voluntary actions and goodwill. Both politics and
economics could reduce the chance of this happening.
The political language of competition, which has been
emanating from central government from Keith Joseph in the
1980s to Andrew Adonis, continues to emphasise the importance
of competition as a central dynamic to improve schools. We
should not then be surprised if schools put their own
interests before those of the wider community.
And competition will be made all the sharper, at a time of
falling pupil numbers, by the knowledge that keeping up one's
reputation and client base will become ever more important for
the economic survival of each individual school.
Donald Hirsch is an international consultant on education
policy